From: Rick Anderson <[log in to unmask]>
Date: Tue, 6 Nov 2018 11:07:26 +0000

But if I understand the case law that has followed from the Sherman Act, a monopoly doesn’t lose its innocence by virtue of mere market dominance; it loses its innocence when it arises from businesses engaging in a “combination... or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce.” (The quote is from Section 3 of the Sherman Act, the full text of which can be found at https://tinyurl.com/ycvnagfg, for those interested.) As far as I can see—and please, if I’ve missed something in the complaint please correct me—no one is accusing Elsevier of conspiring with any other business in order to undermine competition in the market.

 

Tennant’s and Brembs’ real complaint seems to be against scholarly publishing itself, which (they correctly point out) is not a market of substitutes. But that’s not the fault of Elsevier or of anyone else; it arises from the simple fact that what scholarship produces are more-or-less unique documents: generally speaking, no two biology or sociology or physics articles are similar enough in content that one of them could functionally substitute for the other—if they were, we would strongly suspect one of the authors of plagiarism. This means that monopoly control of the market for any individual product of scholarship is inevitable and will always rest with its copyright holder (in the form of an “innocent monopoly,” as you point out, Kevin). Unless, of course, the copyright is broken—either literally (by the work being placed in the public domain) or functionally (by the work being licensed to the public under CC BY or its equivalent).

 

In any case, I can’t see how the innocent monopoly that I hold over the market for my article suddenly becomes nefarious when I transfer my copyright to a publisher—let alone how it becomes uniquely nefarious when transferred to Elsevier in particular. In neither case is there any conspiracy between putative competitors for the purpose of exerting illegal control over a market.

 

---

Rick Anderson

Assoc. Dean for Collections & Scholarly Communication

Marriott Library, University of Utah

Desk: (801) 587-9989

Cell: (801) 721-1687

[log in to unmask]

 

 

From: "Smith, Kevin L" <[log in to unmask]>

Date: Sun, 4 Nov 2018 19:19:49 +0000

I am not an anti-trust expert by any means, but I think the answer to this, and to the same question posed by Rick, is straightforward. The limited monopoly held by individual authors is not a problem — it is an “innocent” monopoly, just like my exclusive rights over by house — because it does not convey market dominance.  The monopolist problem the complaint outlines is quite different, where a large conglomeration of monopolies over content are exercised in order to dominate a market and to exclude competition. The line that is allegedly crossed has to be define within the terms of a particular market, of course, which is precisely what competition authorities are charged to do.

 

Kevin

 

On Nov 4, 2018, at 12:47 PM, LIBLICENSE <[log in to unmask]> wrote:

From: Kent Anderson <[log in to unmask]>

Date: Fri, 2 Nov 2018 06:42:35 -0700

Can someone explain to me what a “monopoly over articles” means compared to the cultural expectations prohibiting duplicate publication and plagiarism? Isn’t every article locked down by these expectations and norms, moreso than by copyright?

 

Also, not all publishers require copyright transfer, so if this were an issue for an author group, authors could shop for publishers who don’t. The market would respond, and to some extent has responded. Isn’t copyright transfer a market condition susceptible to market pressures?

 

But the first question is the one I’m most curious about. What would “non-monopolized” articles look like? Any different?

 

-- 
Kent Anderson

CEO, RedLink and RedLink Network

57 East Main Street, Suite 211

Westborough, MA  01581

Phone: 508-366-5653

Cell: 774-288-9464

ORCID: 0000-0002-5458-6735

 

[snip]